The Capitalist Workday, the Socialist Workday

 

(Transcript of a talk given in Venezuela on May Day.)

On May Day, there are four things that are worth remembering:

  1. For workers, May Day does not celebrate a state holiday or gifts from the state but commemorates the struggle of workers from below.
  2. The initial focus of May Day was a struggle for the shorter workday.
  3. The struggle for the shorter workday is not an isolated struggle but is the struggle against capitalist exploitation.
  4. The struggle against capitalist exploitation is an essential part but not the only part of the struggle against capitalism.

What I am going to do in this talk today is to set out some ideas about the capitalist workday and the socialist workday which I hope can be useful in the current struggles around the world.

The Capitalist Workday

What is the relation between the capitalist workday and exploitation?  When workers work for capital, they receive a wage which allows them to purchase a certain amount of commodities.  How much is that wage? There is nothing automatic about the wage level. It is determined by the struggles of workers against capital.

Those commodities which form the worker’s wage contain a certain quantity of labour, and those hours of labour on a daily basis are often described as the “necessary labour” of the worker—the hours of labour necessary for workers to produce the commodities they consume on a daily basis.

But, in capitalism workers do not just work their hours of necessary labour. Because they have been compelled to sell their ability to work to the capitalist in order to survive, the capitalist is in the position to demand they work longer than this.  And the difference between their hours of necessary labour and the total work that workers perform for capital is surplus labour—the ultimate source of capital’s profits. In other words, capitalist profits are based on the difference between the workday and necessary labour; they are based upon surplus labour, unpaid labour, exploitation.

So, the more the capitalist is able to drive up the workday, the greater the exploitation and the greater the profit.  Marx commented that “the capitalist is constantly tending to reduce wages to their physical minimum and extend the working day to its physical maximum”. How true. Marx continued, though, and noted “while the working man constantly presses in the opposite direction”.  In other words, class struggle: workers struggle to increase wages and to reduce the workday; they struggle to reduce exploitation by capitalists.

Of course, your workday is more than just the time spent between clocking in and clocking out.  There is the time it takes you to get to work, the time it takes to buy the food you need to survive, the time to prepare that food—all this is really necessary labour and part of the worker’s workday.  But since this labour is free to the capitalist, since it is not a cost for him, it is therefore invisible to him. So, when the capitalists want to drive down necessary labour by driving down wages (or by increasing productivity relative to wages), it is not the labour he does not pay for that he wants to reduce.  Rather, he wants as much free labour as possible, as much unpaid labour as possible.

It is not surprising that workers want to reduce their unpaid labour for capital and do so by struggling to reduce the capitalist workday.  But it is not only the unpaid labour in the workday that is a burden for workers; it is also the paid labour that they are compelled to do for capital. In other words, the problem is not only exploitation. It is the way that capitalist production deforms working people. In the capitalist workplace, the worker works for the goals of capital, under the control of capital and with an organisation of production which is designed not to permit workers to develop their capabilities but, rather, has the single goal of profits. “All means for the development of production”, Marx stressed about capitalism, “distort the worker into a fragment of a man, they degrade him” and “alienate from him the intellectual potentialities of the labour process”. In other words, the process of capitalist production cripples us as human beings. Life in the capitalist workplace is a place where we are commanded from above, where we are mere tools that capital manipulates in order to get profits.

That is why we want to reduce the capitalist workday. That is why we cannot wait to escape. It is not only the exploitation, the unfairness and the injustice in the distribution of income. Time away from capitalist production appears as the only time in which we can be ourselves, a time when our activity can be free time, time for the full development of the individual.

This is what it necessarily looks like within capitalism. But we have to recognise that so many of our ideas within capitalism are infected. The most obvious example is the phenomenon of consumerism—we must buy all those things! What we own defines us. The socialist answer, though, is not that everyone should own the same things—in other words, equalisation of alienation; rather, the socialist idea is to end the situation in which we are owned and defined by things.

The battle of ideas, which is central to the struggle for socialism, is based on the alternative conception of socialism. Its focus is not to reform this or that idea that has developed within capitalism but, rather, to replace ideas from capitalism with conceptions appropriate to socialism.  So, is our idea of the workday within capitalism infected? And, can we get any insights into the workday by thinking about the workday within socialism?

The Socialist Workday

Firstly, what do we mean by socialism?  The goal of socialists has always been the creation of a society which would allow for the full development of human potential. It was never seen as a society in which some people are able to develop their capabilities and others are not. That was Marx’s point in stating clearly that the goal is “an association, in which the free development of each is the condition for the free development of all.” And this is clearly the point, too, of Venezuela’s Bolivarian constitution where it stresses in article 20 that “everyone has the right to the free development of his or her own personality” and in the explicit recognition in article 299 that the goal of a human society must be that of “ensuring overall human development”.

In contrast to capitalist society, where “the worker exists to satisfy the need” of capital to expand, Marx envisioned a socialist society where the wealth that workers have produced “is there to satisfy the worker’s own need for development”. So, what is the nature of the workday in a society oriented toward ensuring overall human development?

Let us begin by talking about necessary labour—quantitatively. There is the labour which is contained in the products we consume daily—just like before. To this, however, we need to add the labour that workers want to devote toward expanding production in the future. In socialism, there are no capitalists who compel the performance of surplus labour and invest a portion of the profits in the search for future profits. Rather, workers themselves in their workplaces and society decide if they want to devote time and effort to expanding satisfaction of needs in the future. If they make this decision, then this labour is not surplus to their needs; it forms part of what they see as their necessary labour. Thus, the concept of necessary labour changes here.

In a socialist society, further, we recognise explicitly that part of our necessary labour is labour within the household. In other words we acknowledge that our workday does not begin after we leave the household but includes what we do within the household. Article 88 of the Bolivarian constitution recognises the importance of this labour when it notes that labour within the household is “economic activity that creates added value and produces social welfare and wealth”. 

The concept of necessary labour and our workday within a socialist society also includes the labour which is required to self-govern our communities. After all, if socialism is about the decisions we make democratically in our communities, then the time we need to do this is part of our necessary labour. Similarly, if socialism is about creating the conditions in which we are all able to develop our potential, then the process of education and of developing our capabilities is also activity which is necessary.

When we think about the socialist workday, in short, we think about the workday differently. Our view of the quantity of necessary labour, for example, is not distorted by the capitalist perspective of treating as necessary only that labour for which capital must pay. That is the difference between the political economy of capital and the political economy of the working class. From the perspective of workers, we recognise as necessary labour all the labour that is necessary for “the worker’s own need for development”.

But the difference is not only quantitative. In socialism, the workday cannot be a day in which you receive orders from the top (even in strategic industries). Rather, it is only through our own activity, our practice and our protagonism that we can develop our capabilities. Article 62 of Venezuela’s constitution makes that point in its declaration that participation by people is “the necessary way of achieving the involvement to ensure their complete development, both individual and collective”.  In other words, in every aspect of our lives (the traditional workplace, the community, the household), democratic decision making is a necessary characteristic of the socialist workday; through workers’ councils, communal councils, student councils, family councils, we produce ourselves as new socialist subjects.

Thus, when we look at the workday from the perspective of socialism, we see that the simple demand for reducing the workday is a demand from within capitalism. Its message is simple—end this horror! This is an “infected” conception of the workday. It starts from a view of labour as so miserable that the only thing you can think of doing is reducing and ending it.

When we think about building socialism, however, we recognise that the demand is to transform the workday—to recognise all parts of our workday explicitly and to transform that day qualitatively.  Rather than only “free time” being time in which we can develop, from the perspective of socialism it is essential to make the whole day time for building human capacities.

In short, there are two ways of looking at the demand for the reduced workday: one way talks simply about a shorter work week and thus longer weekend vacations; in contrast, a second way stresses the reduction of the traditional workday in order to provide the time on a daily basis for education for self-managing, for our work within the household and our work within our communities.  In other words, it is the demand to redefine and transform our workday.

The first of these is simply a reform within capitalism.  For socialists, May Day should be the day to struggle for the whole worker’s day, to struggle for the socialist workday.

(Michael A. Lebowitz is professor emeritus of economics at Simon Fraser University in Vancouver, Canada.)

Read more

Subscribe to Janata Weekly Newsletter & WhatsApp Channel

Help us increase our readership.
If you are enjoying reading Janata Weekly, DO FORWARD THE WEEKLY MAIL to your mailing list and invite people to subscribe for FREE!